Ch. 16: Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Capital Structure
- Capital Structure is the amount of debt and equity a firm uses as its sources of capital.
- How should a manager decide between debt and equity financing?
- What should the manager’s goal be?
- Maximize shareholder value.
- When does this differ from maximizing firm value?
- How does maximizing firm value relate to WACC?
- Management should choose capital structure to maximize shareholder wealth. This can be achieved by maximizing firm value or minimizing WACC.
- How can management alter capital structure?
- Increase leverage
- Increase debt
- Reduce equity by repurchasing shares (paying a dividend)
- Decrease leverage
- Retire outstanding debt
- Issue new equity
Effect of Leverage
Break-even EBIT
- We are trying to find the Earnings Before Interest and Taxes (EBIT) where the Earnings Per Share (EPS) is the same under both the current and proposed capital structures.
- See Figure 16.1.
- If we expect the EBIT to be greater than the break-even point, then leverage may be beneficial to our stockholders.
- If we expect the EBIT to be less than the break-even point, then leverage is detrimental to our stockholders.
- Conclusions
- The effect of financial leverage depends on the company’s EBIT. When EBIT is relatively high, leverage is beneficial.
- Under the expected scenario, leverage increases the returns to shareholders, as measured by both ROE and EPS.
- Shareholders are exposed to more risk under the proposed capital structure because the EPS and ROE are much more sensitive to changes in EBIT in this case.
- Because of the impact that financial leverage has on both the expected return to stockholders and the riskiness of the stock, capital structure is an important consideration.
Homemade Leverage
- Why is this last conclusion not the case?
- As an investor, I can use personal borrowing to undo the capital structure decisions of the manager.
- If the proposed capital structure from the previous example is not implemented, how can I get equivalent exposure to the levered case?
- I am interested in owning 100 shares in the levered firm.
- I can achieve this payoff by buying 100 shares outright and buying 100 shares by borrowing at 10%.
Modigliani-Miller Theorem
- Three cases
- No corporate taxes, no personal taxes, no bankruptcy costs
- Corporate taxes, no personal taxes, no bankruptcy costs
- Corporate taxes, no personal taxes, Bankruptcy costs
- Two Propositions
- Firm Value
- Can change due to the riskiness of cash flows
- Can change due to changing the cash flows (amounts and timing)
- WACC and Systematic Risk
Capital Structure Theory without Taxes
- Modigliani-Miller Proposition I
- The value of the firm is not affected by changes in the capital structure.
- The cash flows of the firm do not change; therefore, value doesn’t change.
- Modigliani-Miller Proposition II
- WACC is not influenced by capital structure.
- $WACC = R_A = \frac{E}{V} R_E + \frac{D}{V} R_D$
- $R_E = R_A + \frac{D}{E}(R_A-R_D)$
- See Figure 16.3.
- Examples
- Required return on assets = 16%; Cost of debt = 10%; Percent of debt = 45%. What is the cost of equity?
- Required return on assets = 16%; Cost of debt = 10%; Cost of equity = 25%. What is the Debt-to-Equity ratio?
- How does financial leverage change systematic risk?
- Plug CAPM into above equation.
- $\beta_E = \beta_U + \frac{D}{E}(\beta_U - \beta_D)$
- If debt is riskless, $\beta_E = \beta_U (1 + \frac{D}{E})$.
Capital Structure Theory with Taxes
- Modigliani-Miller Proposition I
- When a firm adds debt, it reduces taxes.
- The reduction in taxes increase the firm’s cash flows.
- The value of the firm increases by the present value of the annual interest tax shield ($(T_c \times D \times R_D)/R_D = T_c \times D$).
- $V_L = \frac{EBIT(1-T_c)}{R_U} + DT_c$
- Example: EBIT = $\$$25 million; Tax rate = 35%; Debt = $75 million; Cost of debt = 9%; Unlevered cost of capital = 12%.
- See Figure 16.4.
- Modigliani-Miller Proposition II
- WACC decrease with leverage because the government subsidizes interest expenses.
- $WACC = R_A = \frac{E}{V} R_E + \frac{D}{V} (1-T_c) R_D$
- $R_E = R_U + \frac{D}{E}(1-T_c)(R_U-R_D)$
- See Figure 16.5.
- How does financial leverage change systematic risk?
- Plug CAPM into above equation.
- $\beta_E = \beta_U + (1-T_c) \frac{D}{E} (\beta_U - \beta_D)$
Trade-off Theory of Capital Structure
- As leverage increases, the probability of bankruptcy increases.
- The increase probability of bankruptcy increases the expected bankruptcy costs.
- Bankruptcy Costs
- Direct
- Legal and administrative costs
- Liquidity costs of selling
- Indirect
- Assets lose value as management spends time worrying about avoiding bankruptcy instead of running the business.
- The firm may also lose sales, experience interrupted operations and lose valuable employees.
- The value of the firm is maximized when the costs of bankruptcy exactly offset the present value of the interest tax shield.
- See Figure 16.6.
- See Figure 16.7.
Managerial Recommendations
- The tax benefit is only important if the firm has a large tax liability.
- The risks of financial distress:
- The greater the risk of financial distress, the less debt will be optimal for the firm.
- The cost of financial distress varies across firms and industries, and as a manager you need to understand the cost for your industry.
Pecking-Order Theory
- According to Pecking-Order Theory:
- Use internal financing first.
- Issue debt next.
- Issue new equity as a last resort.
- This theory is at odds with tradeoff-theory:
- There is no target D/E ratio.
- Profitable firms use less debt.
- Companies like financial slack (cash on hand).